Thursday, October 17, 2024

Esau's Hurricane

I checked out Isaac's Storm from the library a few weeks ago. After reading and enjoying The Splendid and The Vile, I heard from a few family members that they had particularly enjoyed Erik Larson's earlier historical narrative about the great hurricane of 1900, which devastated the city of Galveston TX.

 


In between me checking out that book and actually starting to read it, the country has suffered another two historically painful hurricanes, Helene and Milton. While I haven't followed those storms super-closely, there's plenty of news of the devastation and anguish they have caused, and some of that contemporary news was fresh in my mind while reading this. Helene in particular felt kind of similar in the almost unbelievable way it unfolded: nobody had thought that a hurricane could strike the coast of Texas before it did, and nobody imagined that a hurricane could cause such devastation deep in inland North Carolina before it arrived.

As with his other books, Erik Larson writes in a novelistic style with characters, plots, dialogues and tension, but 100% backed by historical data. Every time a character "speaks" in the book, it's based on a contemporary recording. All of their movements and actions are based on data (when necessarily qualified with a "perhaps" or "maybe").

The primary character here is the titular Isaac Cline. A station chief for the nascent Weather Bureau positioned in Galveston, Isaac is uniquely positioned for a perspective on the storm: he's plugged into the Bureau bureaucracy, the science, the Galveston geography, culture, and so on. As with The Splendid and the Vile, though, there's a wide range of "supporting characters" filling the novel as well. One of the most poignant is Joseph, Isaac's younger brother. Joseph and a few other characters reappear thoughout the book, while others may only appear in a single scene.

After a dramatic opening, the book rewinds to the formation of the Weather Bureau and gradually progresses forward to 1900. Pretty much everything here was brand-new information for me. The Bureau started as a wing of the military, which wanted to systematize the gathering and reporting of weather information. Of course this is hugely important for warfare - as is demonstrated in a later meeting, a single hurricane can destroy more warships than enemy cannons, and being able to predict even a few hours out whether it will be rainy or sunny can have a huge impact on the decision to launch an infantry assault.

Isaac grew up in a tiny rural farming community, went to college, and was plucked to join the Bureau; but because it was a military operation, he also needed to practice swordsmanship, horseback riding, and other basic training of the day. A big part of this was signalling, the ancient art of communicating over long distances through flags, smoke fires, mirrors and so on. This wasn't used in practice, thanks to the relatively recent development and spread of the telegraph. Larson notes that prior to the telegraph there wouldn't have been any way for the Weather Bureau to function: it relied on near-instantaneous communication across a vast amount of space, collecting data in near real-time to get a better understanding of what systems were active and how they were moving. As with most books I read these days, I was reminded of William Bernstein, particularly The Birth of Plenty and its argument that the creation of the telegraph was the final pre-requisite for creating the modern economy.

I was a little surprised at first to learn that the modern National Weather Service started as a creation of the military, but in retrospect it makes a lot of sense. More recently, the Internet, GPS, Roombas and many other things were directly spawned by US military research and development, before spinning off and creating enormous civilian benefits.

It was cool to read about the start of weather forecasting as a science. I've recently been thinking about the origin of psychology and psychiatry. Prior to Freud, the mind was generally thought of as belonging to the religious/spiritual domain, something to discuss with your priest and not with a doctor or scientist. Like many founders of new sciences, Freud was wrong about most of the stuff he wrote about, and he promulgated some specific ideas that caused harm for multiple generations until they were eventually disproved and unwound. But Freud does deserve credit for creating a system around the mind, treating it as something that can be analyzed, experimented on and understood.

It's surprising how similar weather is. Isaac's Storm describes that many people thought it was blasphemous to attempt to predict the weather, because God creates the weather and only He knows what will happen. Much like Freud, the early Weather Bureau was almost comically bad at making forecasts: predicting clear skies immediately before enormous snowfalls, predicting warm weather right before steep freezes. But during this time they were systematically gathering data, refining their techniques and eventually learning from their mistakes and turning into the much more trustworthy National Weather Service we have today.

The NWS still isn't perfectly accurate, of course, as the two recent hurricanes demonstrate. But a huge and important change between 1900 and 2024 has been the embracing of humility. At the time of Isaac's Storm, it was official policy to deny any errors and spin misses into successes. Larson notes in the Afterword that today forecasters are far more willing to admit what they don't know. There's a high level of awareness that things can happen which have never happened before (like massive flooding in the mountains of North Carolina). Acknowledging these limits leads to some more couching, but also far more trust.

The storm itself is highly dramatic, but the human element was even more striking to me: the hubris and arrogance that not only kept people from preparing for the storm, but even know that it was coming. The most infuriating aspect is rooted around imperialism and racism: meteorologists on Cuba had spent several decades developing a very advanced forecasting tradition, drawing on the long knowledge of enduring Caribbean storms and recent scientific advancements. The Weather Bureau was also present on Cuba, and pooh-poohed the idea that the Cubans could predict better than them: they saw Cubans as ignorant superstitious barbarians. Their rivalry grew so intense that the Bureau actually blocked any telegraphs from leaving Cuba without first going through them, and they censored any predictions they didn't agree with. The Cubans correctly recognized that the storm was continuing west and would hit Texas, while the Bureau clung to their prior assumption that hurricanes invariably turn north and would enter through Florida. Even days after the disaster, the Bureau brass refused to recognize that the hurricane which devastated Galveston was the same one that had passed through Cuba days before.

There are of course many examples in human history of mankind turning a tragedy into a catastrophe, but the one that first comes to my mind is Chernobyl, as depicted in the excellent recent HBO miniseries. There as here, powerful natural forces cause the direct damage, but it is human arrogance, stubbornness, and clinging to bureaucracy that makes the situation far worse. The good news is that, in both cases, we can find ways to improve our systems: allowing for dissent, making hierarchies less rigid, being able to at least recognize the possibility of black swan events.

Most of what I've written about here has to do with the Bureau and stuff, which honestly interested me the most, but there's a lot of great personal drama in this book as well. Joseph Cline emerges as possibly the most poignant character of the book. When he's first introduced, I thought of him as the "lesser brother", and imagined him consumed by bitterness and jealousy of his more successful older brother; but by the end of the book he comes across as by far the more admirable brother: more honest, less self-aggrandizing, very brave.

I loved the rivalry between Galveston and Houston. I think that's one of those things that's hard for us to really appreciate from our modern standpoint: knowing how things end, it's hard to take Galveston seriously as a contender, but Larson does a great job at portraying just how optimistic city leaders were about their future destiny. That's another thing that felt uniquely turn-of-the-century, the kind of civic boosterism that seemingly prevailed everywhere west of the Appalachians. While Houston makes very few direct appearances here, each specific one is loaded with significance. The book ends with the discovery of the Spindletop gusher and the massive wealth that subsequently flowed to Houston and Texas; this lines up in some ways with Chernow's biography of Rockefeller, which likewise pays very little attention to Texas other than noting how oddly long it took for anyone to discover significant oil reserves outside of western Pennsylvania.

Near the end of the book, while the storm ravages Galveston, we see some really macabre scenes. One of the most affecting describes how, as the storm was growing more intense, the nuns at an orphanage attempted to protect the children by collecting them in groups and connecting them together with a rope line, keeping anyone from getting lost. After the storm passed, a rescuer found a dead child on the beach, and when attempting to retrieve the body, dragged up another dozen bodies and a nun's. The rope that was meant to protect them all ended up dooming them all.

Anecdotes like that help communicate the gravity of the destruction. Reading the death toll numbers sounds bad - early reports put it at a few hundred, then over a thousand, and eventually as many as 10,000. But personally I have a hard time emotionally connecting to a raw statistic: 100, 1000, 10000 deaths all sound bad. Having those personal stories really helps humanize the particular losses, which you can then extrapolate out to the scale of the suffering.

So, yeah! Not the most cheerful book I've read, but a really compelling and shockingly readable one. I finished almost the entire book in a single day, which is almost unheard of for me: I'll typically plug away at something over a week or more during transit rides and occasional evenings, but this particular one I picked up on a Saturday morning and had almost finished by the time I went to bed. Larson is a terrific writer, taking an incident I was barely aware of, illuminating it, placing it in the historical context and drawing some really great lessons from it.

Tuesday, October 15, 2024

Iron Lung

A common joke among Paradox Grand Strategy game players goes something like "I have 400 hours in this game, so I'm almost done with the tutorial." It's a truer statement than you might think. These games are dense. It isn't just that they have steep learning curves, but that there is so much to learn, and almost everything is interlocked with everything else. It's incredibly satisfying to feel your brain grow and stretch as you learn the game, but also extremely daunting.

 


 

I recently picked up Hearts of Iron IV on a Steam Sale. It's been on my radar for a while, as are all of the other games in this portfolio. Very roughly:

  • Imperator: Rome: ~300BC - ~1AD
  • Crusader Kings: ~900 - 1453
  • Europa Universalis: 1444 - 1821
  • Victoria: 1836 - 1936
  • Hearts of Iron: 1936 - 1948
  • Stellaris: 2200 - 2500

I've mostly been interested in Victoria and HoI due to my increasing interest in economic and social developments during this era. It seemed like a fun way to dig a bit deeper into these ideas and maybe play around with some alternate-history scenarios.

 


 

I came to this game with a false sense of confidence in mastering its mechanics. After all, I've already gotten decent at EU4 and Stellaris, and all of these games are built on the same Clausewitz engine. Obviously the HOI4 timeline is much more compact, but surely it would be a lot easier to master my third Paradox game.

So far, that has not proven to be true! There are some graphical similarities - in particular, the use of real-world provinces drawn on actual maps (as opposed to Civ-style square or hex translations of geography), and the menus have the same very dense appearance. But the mechanics are hugely different. In no particular order:

 


Combat is much more granular, particularly in your troop design. I suppose the ship designer in Stellaris is a very rough analogue, but a significant part of the game revolves around designing your divisions: how many infantry, artillery, etc. to put in a single division template, then how those divisions are assembled into armies and army groups. Where Stellaris and EU4 just has a handful of stats to track (like "Sublight Speed" or "Shock"), there are far more in HOI.

There are entirely separate map modes for infantry, navy, and air units, and each of them work significantly differently from the others. In EU4 and Stellaris these units are different but interact on the same map.

The economy is completely different, being resource-driven as opposed to money-driven. In Stellaris, "Energy" is your main currency; in EU4, "Ducats". There is no equivalent to those in HOI4. Instead, you produce specific resources: aluminum, steel, oil, rubber, etc. Those resources are required to make the equipment that supplies your troops that fill your divisions that get deployed to the field. If you're low on resources, you'll need to trade for them, or conquer for them.

Oddly, while the design of units is much more tactical in this game, actual warfare is much more strategic. You'll typically declare a "front line", assemble troops near the border, and develop a battle plan that defines your objective. Once the plan starts, though, your troops move mostly on autopilot: they'll find the appropriate areas to assault, fall back to recover when pressed too far, jump back into the fray when ready, flank and encircle enemies when they can, defend against counterattacks, and continue their big-picture advance until their objective is secured. There's almost no babysitting (at least in my limited gametime so far), just occasionally checking in on their progress, which is a huge difference from the more hands-on wars of Stellaris and EU4.

Technology is much more like the classic Civilization tree than either the anonymous EU tree (where you're researching without knowing exactly what you'll discover) or the semi-randomized Stellaris cluster (gradually unlocking higher "tiers" but largely free of prerequisites, with only a few options available of many unlocked at any given point). In HOI4, you can see the entire tree from the start, and can pick any item available from the tree. Given the short timeline, these are very granular: you can research a very specific model of a battleship, or something that will improve the productivity of your refining plants, along with a few genuinely transformational technologies like Radio and Nuclear Fission. (Which is a great reminder of the incredible strides in science that occurred in an astonishing short number of years!)

 


Leaders are a bit like Stellaris commanders (nee Admirals and Generals) or EU4 military leaders. But, as with most combat, they are much more granular, with a huge tree of unlockable options. Those options are kind of like Traits in Stellaris, but are almost entirely player-driven (though leaders do often start with a few and may occasionally unlock some during combat).

A quick summary of my own game:

The in-game tutorial has you playing as Italy from 1936, which is actually a pretty great way to learn the game. You start off fighting a war against Ethiopia, which is significantly weaker than you. In most of these games I specifically try to avoid war for my first game or two so I can master the other systems before taking on that added complexity; in HOI4, though, I'm finding actual combat a lot easier than the economic/production/recruitment system, so learning that first works well.

 


The tutorial is well-designed and integrated into the game, which I appreciated and did not take for granted; I still remember when the in-game EU3 tutorial was completely broken because it required objectives that were no longer present after a more recent update to the game. Following the guide I massed troops at the northern and southern borders and ordered them to converge in Addis Ababa. My northern wing made swift advances and captured the capital soon; movement and fighting were significantly slower in the south, with long, drawn-out combat all along the front. I'm not sure if this is because my northern force had air support and the southern didn't, because my northern force had a higher-ranked general, or just more troops. If I were to play this again, I would relocate my entire air force (mostly based in Italy but also with some wings in Libya and elsewhere) and provide more support throughout the theater.

 


The tutorial proper ends with the annexation of Ethiopia, but after that the in-game Decisions / objectives / goals take over. These give great mid-level targets to work towards, including things like stamping out resistance and increasing compliance in Ethiopia, building more factories, recruiting more soldiers, etc. They work as a sort of extended tutorial, prompting you to figure out how to do these things.

Shortly after the Ethiopian war wrapped, the Spanish Civil War broke out. A big part of the reason I bought this game in the first place was a fantasy of leading the FAI/CNT to victory, but in this game I followed the historical precedent of sending "volunteers" to assist the Nationalists. This introduced a whole other set of mechanics, with an entirely separate theater for this war, but also gave me a lot of valuable (real-life) (though I guess also in-game!) experience with combat. I only had three units there, but got to observe a lot of battles, including my first glimpse of Soviet tanks. We inserted in the northwest and managed to (re-)conquer the north coast. Around this time the Catalan Free Republic revolted, starting a three-way war against the Nationalists and Republicans. I stayed focused on the Republicans, the CFR was able to conquer a good chunk of the Republicans and then got chunked by the Nationalists and their Reich allies.

 


Japan declared on China during the Spanish Civil War. In both cases, I improved relations with the fascist countries for a few weeks, then sent attachés. This ended up pretty much completely consuming my Command Power (50 CP for each attaché, plus 20 for each of my Military Cabinet ministers), but gives a significant source of XP even without fighting.

Probably my favorite part of HOI4 so far has been the Focus Tree. This is somewhat similar to the Mission Tree of EU4, but is more like a tech tree in that you select one item and spend some time to progress it rather than having a discrete goal to work towards. This seems to be where a lot of the historical and alt-historical aspects of HOI4 come about: I initially followed a fairly accurate path dealing with creation of military police in Africa and developing that region, along with some scientific and industrial reforms; more recently, I have been getting heavily involved in the Balkans, variously propping up pretenders to thrones, bullying small nations into personal unions, and outright taking small states. I recently created the Italian Confederation faction, severing the possibility of cooperation with the Reich. There are tons of other directions to go in, though, including (if the war in Ethiopia leads to the disgrace and removal of Mussolini) a rekindling of the Great War alliance with France and England; or a communist uprising and joining with the Communist Faction. There's even a path to creating a new Roman Empire, just like the Mare Nostrum achievement of EU4.

 


So, where do I go from here? I'm not sure! Part of me wants to muddle further along as Italy as I try to grok the systems at play. Another part wants to try that Spanish Republic game. Or some other alternate history path, like a Trotskyist revolution in the Soviet Union.

 


Or I may just pause this indefinitely. I am reminded that war is usually one of my least favorite parts of 4X/Grand Strategy games, and in retrospect picking up the entirely war-focused Hearts Of Iron may not have been the smartest move on my part! I have been feeling freshly tempted to start a new EU4 game (despite knowing that can be a several-hundreds-hours-long commitment) or firing up Stellaris again. But this may all be moot if it turns out that Dragon Age Veilguard is good after all. We will see!

Sunday, October 13, 2024

Democracy (Yeah You Know Me)

As usual, the 2024 California ballot is a long one! I usually know out the gate how I'll be voting in the political races, but the propositions and measures usually take a bit more research. For future reference, here is how I am casting my vote!



President and Vice President: Kamala D. Harris and Tim Walz

Senator: Adam B. Schiff (ugh)

Senator Again For Some Reason: Adam B. Schiff (still ugh)

US Representative: Kevin Mullin

State Senator: Josh Becker

Assembly Member: Diane Papan

San Mateo County Board of Education: Maurice Goodman

Proposition 2 (bonds for schools): Yes

Proposition 3 (constitutional right to gay marriage): Yes

Proposition 4 (bonds for water projects): Yes

Proposition 5 (lowers required local votes for housing bonds to 55%): Yes

Proposition 6 (abolish forced labor in prisons): Yes

Proposition 32 (raise minimum wage): Yes

Proposition 33 (allows local rent control): Yes

Proposition 34 (revenge for Prop 33): No

Proposition 35 (medi-cal funding): No (I actually like what this would do, but it should be handled by the legislature, not a proposition)

Proposition 36 (repeal Prop 47, re-felonize most thefts): No

Measure J (Millbrae elementary school bond funding): Yes

Measure FF (Expand city council term limits from 2 consecutive to 3 consecutive): No


I have increasingly mixed feelings on our top-two primary/election system. I feel like early on it was really effective for shaking up ineffective but entrenched Democratic incumbents, and let to much more dynamic and competitive elections. In recent years, though, at least at the statewide level, the (usually centrist) Democrats have come up with an effective playbook of elevating marginal Republican candidates who can't win in a general election, so they can coast to an easy victory instead of competing against another Democrat who has a shot. The Harris/Sanchez and Feinstein/DeLeon races were actually interesting, while Schiff/Garvey is not. I increasingly think that ranked-choice with instant runoff is the way to go.

For better or worse, the fall elections can be simplified quite a bit thanks to candidates running unopposed in the first round or (for some races) a candidate winning by a huge margin and skipping the "runoff". Just a reminder to vote in every election to make sure that your vote actually counts, and to see the candidate(s) you'd like to see!

I'm taking a bit of a chill-pill in this election on my standard "vote No on Bonds" principle. I don't really have a great reason for that, more just a general feeling that these are worthy enough projects to overcome my dislike of bonds.

I am feeling a slight amount of relief at casting my vote early, but obviously still have plenty of angst to spare between now and the election. Living in California and the Bay Area, there aren't many competitive races or measures to focus on. If you're like me and have some extra bucks that you'd like to send to a good political cause, I recently started using Oath. This gives a good way to find down-ballot races throughout the country, races that are spending thousands instead of millions of dollars and where your donations can make an outsized impact. They have a pretty nice interface where you can filter by causes you're most passionate about (like climate change, gun safety, mental health, etc.) and specific states. You can donate to specific candidates, which I generally like more than giving to committees and organizations. (The great thing about Oath is that they only focus on competitive elections, so you aren't tempted to waste your money on high-profile but hopeless challengers to, like, Mitch McConnell or Marjorie Taylor Green.) And unlike a lot of other platforms, Oath doesn't share your email address with the candidates, which helps cut down on inbox spam.

So, yeah! I have lots of Thoughts and Feelings about this election, but probably nothing that would surprise long-term readers, so I may or may not write that up in a separate post. I hope everyone stays safe & practices good self-care during this intense time!

Wednesday, October 09, 2024

Spar

Nicola Griffith has become one of my go-to authors: as soon as I hear of a new book from her, I know I'll pick it up. Not necessarily on Day One, but I immediately look forward to reading it, and avoid any reviews, summaries or other information that may color my initial reading.

 



In a bit of reverse chronology, I finished reading Spear (written in 2022) after Menewood (written in 2023). I think that in my mind I had somewhat conflated the two: they're both set in England near the middle of the first millennium and (as usual for Griffith) feature awesome lady protagonists.

MINI SPOILERS

They are pretty different, though. Menewood, like Hild before it, is a doorstop of a book, while Spear is much briefer at just around 150 pages. Both books feel anchored in their historical moments and geographical places, while also inviting in a sense of mysticism: but in Hild/Menewood that mysticism is itself grounded in history, and we can see both the secular origins of mystery and the effect it has on peoples' minds; in Spear, the magic actually is real, and the novel slowly grows in the direction of myth and legend.

It took quite a while into Spear for me to get a bead on the question of "is magic real or not". The protagonist is initially nameless, just known as "the girl" or "her." Eventually, she wins a name for herself: Peretur, referencing her self-trained skill with a spear. She has special qualities from the start of the novel: able to calm animals, to sense changes in the weather. Later on these become increasingly special and uncanny: during a duel in a stream, she recognizes by a movement in her opponent's eyes that there is a root hidden beneath the water, and she is able to avoid stepping in it. It isn't until nearly halfway through the book that we realize she can have actual visions: seeing things far away, or that nobody else can see: not merely heightened senses and keen perception, but a real sixth sense, combining telepathy and divination. This isn't a magic to hurl fireballs or call down rain or compel men: it's a magic that makes her the best at things other people can do.

Unlike Hild, who had great wisdom and carved out a unique role for herself as a "freemartin", protected by her boldness and strangeness, Peretur cloaks herself (literally and figuratively) in a man's garb. She wants to be a fighting companion of the king, and no woman can do that, so she presents herself as a man. Since this is more of a fantasy, she probably could have succeeded without the ruse, but it adds a really great layer to the story. The narrative always refers to Peretur as "she" while the dialogue usually uses "he". I kept half-expecting her to be found out, but that doesn't really happen: a few others do learn, but only when she chooses to share with them.

MEGA SPOILERS

It's great fun to discover, surprisingly far into the book, that this is a reimagining of one of the Arthurian legends. We start to hear of King Artos, also called Arturus; later on we meet Llanza, Gwenhwyfair, Myrddin and others - all very Welsh, obviously. Peretur herself turns out to be Sir Percival, who discovers the Holy Grail.

One of the things I liked best about this book was how, when you learn new things later in the book, they illuminate things from earlier in the story. One of the biggest examples is the bowl: one of Peretur's earliest memories is the black, decorated bowl that her mother Elen used for water and cooking. Much later, we learn that this bowl is one of the four great treasures of the Tuatha: her mother stole it from Manandan, one of these godlike creatures, as revenge and payment for her captivation. I'm pretty sure that this is the same item as the Cauldron as depicted in Lloyd Alexander's Black Cauldron; in this book, it's one and the same as the Grail as in the Quest for the Holy Grail. And this bowl/cup/grail/cauldron is the source of Peretur's great abilities: the bowl confers immortality, and by casually drinking from it from a young age, Petetur has absorbed god-like abilities.

As with many of Griffith's other novels, this one features an excellent romance. There's a sweet casual-ish connection between the young Peretur and an innkeeper's daughter that in some ways reminded me of Hild's "bed games", simultaneously sweet and no-strings-attached. The main romance is between Peretur and Nimue, Myrddin's apprentice and captor. Once again, there's a unique spin on the classic mythology here: Nimue is once again a young woman who learns sorcery from Merlin and eventually imprisons him: but in Spear, Myrddin is a manipulative jerk, stealing Nimue's power while pretending to grant his to her, and shaping her into an accomplice to help seize the Tuath treasures. Rather than a betrayal, her imprisonment of Myrddin is an act of justice. Anyways, Nimue is understandably wary of Peretur: her magic, her power, and, as we eventually learn, her kinship with Myrddin. But they work through this and secure a really wonderful relationship.

END SPOILERS

The book also includes an afterword that I found really interesting, describing Griffith's long interest since childhood in these kinds of stories, the various historical and literary antecedents of the tales, and how she as a writer found her way into this particular novel. That raised a few connections I had missed while reading the book but that make perfect sense in retrospect.

The timing of this post is somewhat fortuitous, as Nicola just announced today the republication of her Aud Torvingen novels! I don't think I ever blogged about these since I felt like I didn't have anything particularly insightful to say, but I highly enjoyed them: great hard-boiled modern noir mysteries with (as usual) a vivid and compelling protagonist and sharp writing. She has previously blogged about the ordeal in dealing with these books: although it is a linear trilogy, each had a separate publisher, and none of them were ever motivated to publicize the other books or offer a unified visual appearance. After a LONG time she got the rights back, and I'm sure she's thrilled to finally have them presented as she'd like them.

Anyways! I highly enjoyed Spear, and I think just about anyone would like it. It's a much easier commitment than Hild, familiar enough to be accessible, unique enough to be intriguing, with great characters and telling its own flavor of a heroic journey.

Friday, October 04, 2024

Common Sense

I finally read "Common Sense on Mutual Funds" by the late, great John ("Jack") Bogle. I feel like I've been reading around this book for a decade, poking away at Bogle's shorter works and various books by other authors that occupy similar spaces and quote from it. I've enjoyed actually going to the source and directly experiencing it.

 


I read the second edition, published in 2009, and really loved how it's structured: it has the exact same text as the original edition from 1999, but with all of the tables and graphs extended to the right to show the next 10 years of data. He also includes periodic boxes labeled "10 Years Later", within which he adds new commentary on how the additional evidence of the last 10 years has affected his earlier analysis. In nearly every case it confirms his earlier assertions: sometimes he regrets being too cautious in his initial pronouncements, but I can't think of a single instance where he was wildly off the mark. It's especially interesting because the 1999-2009 period was basically the reverse of the 1989-1999 period: the 90s were a period of huge and largely uninterrupted growth, while the 2000s were bracketed by two major bear markets and overall resulted in flat or negative returns. And yet, the overall principles Bogle lays down remained as true in the "winter season" of the future as they had in the "summer season" of the past.

I think that this second-edition update is structured basically like how Burton Malkiel's "A Random Walk Down Wall Street" went in the later editions: he updates the relevant figures and charts, but the overall argument has remained identical over the last five decades. And that's really remarkable for both books! As many others have observed, it's easy to sift through past data and invent a model that would have made money in the past. It's significantly harder to work with "real money", anticipating strategies that will work in the future. Both Malkiel and Bogle have the appropriate humility to recognize the limits of what we know, and solid mathematically-backed arguments for their strategies, with a healthy dose of prior data that generally aligns with their recommendations and that continue to mostly hold true into the future.

This is a big book, but well structured and readable. I enjoyed reading it cover-to-cover, but you could probably dip into specific chapters based on your interest. This is one of the more comprehensive financial books I've read, covering the fundamental theory behind investing, where earnings come from, how the industry is structured, and a strong focus on the cultural and ethical principles at play. Much of the material was already familiar to me, but even the "old stuff" was often treated in more depth or with a new perspective that I found helpful.

For example, he spends a fair amount of time writing about the equity risk premium. This is a term I've heard about a lot in my recent financial reading, and I think I'm finally getting it. In The Four Pillars of Investing, William Bernstein illustrates this principle with the example of a falafel vendor raising money for a restaurant, comparing the option of taking a loan from a bank (low risk to the bank, high risk to the entrepreneur) or finding an investor who will buy an equity stake (low risk to the entrepreneur, high risk to the investor). To entice an investor, the business needs to plausibly offer a return on the investment high enough to offset the risk of losing everything. When Bogle introduces the equity risk premium, he goes right to the real-world example of buying a Treasury versus investing in a stock. If two investments offered the same average return, but one is risk-free and the other is risky, investors would always prefer the risk-free one. In order to attract investors, the riskier investment needs to offer a higher expected (not guaranteed!) return. The difference between the risk-free rate (like a Treasury's interest rate) and the expected return on the riskier investment is the equity risk premium. (To these examples, I'm adding my own of choosing to play a game where you can either get $1M outright, or flip a coin to get either $0M or $2M. The average result of these two choices is identical, but pretty much anyone would choose the $1M guaranteed return. In order to accept the coin flip, you'd need an extra incentive.)

As I read more finance stuff, I've gradually come to realize that some things are pure mathematical relationships, like the inverse relationship between current interest rates and the value of existing bonds. Other things describe trends we have observed over time but that aren't bound to natural laws, such as the P/E ratio, the Equity Risk Premium, and so on. Knowing these general trends and relationships is helpful in understanding the range and probabilities of possible outcomes, but they do not offer any guarantees. One of my favorite sayings in investment is "the market can remain irrational for longer than you can remain solvent." We can recognize that something is out of whack and is overdue for a return to the mean, but there's no way to predict when or how that return will occur.

Anyways, Bogle makes an interesting, nuanced point that I don't think I would have followed if I wasn't already primed for following this from other recent readings. Bogle makes the point in the context of his argument that seemingly small fees can make a huge impact; for example, a 0.2% versus a 2.0% expense ratio for a fund. If a fund has gross returns of 10% annually, then netting 9.8% versus 8% doesn't seem like a huge difference until after you've compounded for several years. But if a T-bill returned 6% over the same period, then you're talking about an equity risk premium of 3.8% versus 2%: essentially a doubled premium for the lower-cost fund. Given a certain (reasonable, though definitely not guaranteed) set of assumptions, he shows how an 80/20 stock/bond portfolio using an actively managed fund may have the same expected return as a 20/80 stock/bond portfolio using indexed funds. The difference is that the 20/80 portfolio bears significantly less risk than the 80/20 portfolio. I'm very used to just looking at (average, expected) returns, and it was cool to see a similarly analytical approach to quantifying the impact of costs on risk and not just reward. Anyways, I think that's neat!!

This idea connects well with William Bernstein's argument for purchasing a liability-matching portfolio. If you have a specific goal, and you can achieve that goal with no risk, then boom: you're done, and can spend the rest of your life assured that you'll never run out of money. Alternatively, you can choose to take on more risk to maximize the growth of your portfolio. Over the very long run (which may be longer than your lifetime!), the latter approach will generate more money. So, yeah: once again, risk is an important thing to consider, and fortunately something that we can think discretely about as opposed to just a hand-waving "being able to sleep at night" attitude.

Returning to mathematical certainties versus empirically-derived correlations: I think Bogle does a good job at describing when he's dealing with one type of relationship versus the other, and is especially forceful with the former and appropriately cautionary with the latter. On the mathematical side, he's insistent that, by definition, all investors as a whole must earn the average return of the market: for every manager who manages to beat the market average, there must be another investor who loses to the market average by the same amount. So (comparatively speaking) "beating the market" is a zero-sum game before costs, and once you take costs into account, more expensive actively-managed funds must, by definition, as a group, under-perform the market average.

What the market average does over time, on the other hand, is empirical, not deductive. Going back to 1820, the stock market has consistently trended upward over the long run. There's no guarantee that it will continue to do so, definitely not during a short term and possibly not over a very long term. So there is risk that investing in the market will result in a loss. But it is a certainty that low-cost (generally indexed) funds will perform better than the average actively-managed fund, whether the market is going up or not.

Bogle has a sense of pride, which I think is pretty well-earned, in creating the first commercially-available index fund, and for being generally correct about how the market works, thanks to insights like predicting long-run market returns based on the current dividend yield plus the growth rate. He claims these wins but isn't obnoxious about it.

The biggest outlier between Bogle and the contemporary Boglehead movement is definitely international investments. Pretty much everyone besides him believes in a significant international exposure; the most common belief today is probably reflecting overall global market capitalization, while many (including myself) overweight the US equity markets while still having a significant minority share of international equities. Bogle argues pretty strongly towards having an all-US portfolio, and grudgingly concedes that you might include up to 20% international for diversification purposes. I've read (and heard) his arguments before, though I think this book handles them at more length and in more depth. They include:

  • The US has significantly better legal protections, liquidity, transparency, regulations, and other helpful aspects to its financial markets.
  • The US has been and remains the global leader in innovation, both creating new successful businesses and growing existing ones.
  • Contrarily, given the demographics of the other fully developed markets (Europe and Japan), he doesn't see much opportunity for future growth: they're already built out, and have aging populations and minimal immigration. More growth is possible in emerging markets, but also significant risk, and it's hard to say with certainty that future returns would be worth it.
  • The largest US companies already have significant international exposure (earning overseas revenue, using overseas labor, etc.), so you already get some diversification while holding only US stocks.
  • Everyone reading this book is a US investor spending US dollars in the US, and international investing exposes you to significant currency risk: a rising dollar will cut into international returns while a weakening dollar will boost them. As with most things in finance, he identifies a long-term reversion to the mean in relative currency strengths. At the time of publication, international stocks had provided great returns; but he notes that this was mostly due to a weakening dollar, and if you correct for the exchange rate, they actually underperformed US markets.

I think it's interesting that the one argument that he seems to (grudgingly) accept as legitimate is diversification, the idea that holding international equities will soften the blow of a broad decline in the US stock market, somewhat like bonds. I think that the diversification hypothesis has been declared dead and buried in the last 15 years: now that we're in a fully globalized world, markets are so interconnected that everything falls when the US does; I'm reminded of the phrase "When America sneezes, the rest of the world catches a cold." We saw this in 2008 (though it may not have been obvious at the time of the second edition) and has continued to hold true since. (Interestingly, the converse has not recently held true, as the US market strongly rebounded from the COVID-19 recession while Europe and Japan continued to languish.)

Pretty much everyone (including modern Bogleheads) disagrees with the rest of his points on international stocks. Taking a crack at summarizing the major counter-arguments I've heard:

  • Reversion to the mean applies to the US as well as everyone else. Outperformance can't last forever.
  • It's mathematically impossible for US outperformance to continue indefinitely, as it would eventually result in a US capitalization of over 100% of global markets.
  • US market strength in the 20th and early 21st century has reflected US dominance (political, military, and economically) over the world. If and when these strengths decline, our market share will as well. In particular, it will be very challenging for the US to remain dominant over countries with significantly larger populations once those countries are fully developed.
It may be worth noting that Bogle wrote this book in the late 90s, and the ~25 years that have passed since then have been pretty friendly to US-only investors; in more recent years, China has emerged as a bigger long-term rival to US supremacy. So Bogle's original advice was very good to people who were reading at the time during their 10-40 year investing journeys, but it's less clear if that will continue for the rest of the century, as he briefly acknowledges in passing.

I also have been enjoying comparing Bogle's arguments with William Bernstein's "Birth of Plenty" thesis. Bernstein identifies a cluster of ingredients (including social norms as well as technology) that create significant and self-sustaining growth. Those are obviously present in the US, were present in Britain before, have been spreading to other advanced economies. But they aren't something you can flip on at will in a developing country: it requires generations of local acceptance and integration. Anyways, if Bernstein is right, then it isn't a slam-dunk that emerging markets will outperform within our lifetimes, or even our children's lifetimes. And, to be a bit more pessimistic, the best we can hope for in the future may be a sustained real growth of ~2% per year in the most advanced countries, including the US, in which case we will be no better but also not significantly worse than anyone else.

I periodically remember how things have changed. At the time that Bogle wrote the first edition of this book, mutual funds (let alone index funds) were still somewhat of an anomaly; most stocks were individually held. By the second edition nearly half of all shares were owned through mutual funds or ETFs; I assume even more are today but am too lazy to look it up. The change is primarily due to higher participation in 401ks, 403bs and IRAs, but I think the diversification and ease of use probably also contribute. I think that the shift towards mutual funds makes his arguments even more relevant, since he's mostly comparing indexed vs. actively managed mutual funds, not so much indexed vs. individual stocks.

The chapter on taxes is really interesting. One thing I hadn't thought of before is how a fund as a whole could have unrealized capital gains thanks to appreciation of its underlying stocks; in his example, if you buy a $100 mutual fund share but there's an unrealized capital gain, then you may only be getting something like $78 worth of stocks for your purchase after accounting for the tax. This tax liability reduces with additional shares, though (since the pre-existing gain is divided among more people), which gives an incentive to grow the fund. He also makes some good points about the value of deferring capital gains; that is not relevant in a tax-advantaged retirement account, but for regular taxable accounts, you can get significant benefits by compounding tax deferrals over a decade or longer. That isn't possible in funds with high turnover, as those gains must be realized when the underlying shares are sold. It seems like tax deferral isn't as relevant for dividend taxes, which must be paid the same year.

Interestingly, both Bogle and Bernstein say it's safest to own the entire market, but Bernstein likes tilting towards value while Bogle seems to slightly prefer tilting towards growth. Over very very very very long periods of time, value stocks have historically returned a bit more than growth; and they don't usually dip as far as growth stocks during downturns, so they're a bit safer to hold in a retirement portfolio. But value stocks tend to return relatively more in dividends, while growth stocks return more in capital appreciation, and Bogle likes how that gives you more control over when and how (or even if) to realize those gains.

Index funds are praised, but are a smaller part of the book than you might think. Bogle would prefer a low-cost managed fund over a high-cost indexed fund, and owning appropriate asset classes is a lot more important than being indexed. He often toys with the idea of directly owning a basket of stocks, and I suspect that he would favor that approach for very wealthy people: mutual and indexed funds are more of a convenience for those of us with extra money to invest but not the deep pockets or professional acumen to assemble our own broadly diversified portfolios. He even supports the idea of very talented managers beating the market; his concern is that you can't identify them in advance, and either they'll close their funds to maintain quality, or expand the fund and practically guarantee future mediocrity.

Early sections of the book cover the same sort of ground as "The Little Book of Common Sense Investing"; the last parts are in the same vein as "The Battle for the Soul of Capitalism", with a little of the autobiographical details of "Enough." So if you're only going to read one Bogle book, this is probably the one that has it all. He writes sternly about the responsibility mutual fund companies hold towards their clients, and how that responsibility is consistently shirked. He eventually names Vanguard and makes a much more direct and impassioned case for why it's special. By this point, hundreds of pages into the book, he's established his intelligence and his values, so it feels deserved.

It's interesting to compare the Bogle-led version of Vanguard as depicted in this book with what exists today. As I've written before, I've been a loyal Vanguard client for decades, but if I were to start investing today I would likely go with Fidelity. Something has changed - no one single decision that made Vanguard lose its way, but a series of decisions over years that he never would have agreed with. One famous one is the introduction of ETFs: Bogle consistently rails against these in the "ten years later" section, and they were brought in essentially over his dead body, after he was forced into retirement. It makes a ton of sense for Vanguard to sell ETFs - investors demand them, and they hew to most of the key Vanguard values like low cost, transparency, and simplicity. But Bogle hated them because they can be (albeit don't have to be) frequently traded like stocks, and so lead people away from the focus on long-term investing that he sees as so critical. More recently, Vanguard has forced all of us legacy users of the mutual fund interface to their new brokerage platform. Again, it makes a lot of sense: it's more economical for them to only support one interface instead of two, and the brokerage site can do almost everything the old mutual fund site could do. But again, being a brokerage is fundamentally about instant gratification, making it easy to buy and sell individual stocks and bonds with the click of a mouse. I can just hear Bogle gnashing his teeth over pushing Vanguard clients away from a long-term-focused platform to the new one.

There's a touching anecdote near the end of the book about how a major institutional investor offered to invest hundreds of millions of dollars into a small-cap short-term bond fund at Vanguard for a few months. It would have been great for the institution since they'd get a major guaranteed return, and it would be great for Vanguard since they'd get the fees and business. But Vanguard rejected it: the existing small investors of the fund would get stuck with the capital gains taxes from that large trade, despite not trading themselves (as good, disciplined long-term investors). The institution was irate, pulled all their business from Vanguard and even wrote a nasty letter in the Wall Street Journal blasting Vanguard. The company lost short-term business, but gained huge respect and loyalty from their existing customers, and attracted many new ones who admired their ethics. I don't see the Vanguard of 2024 making that same decision, and that makes me sad. I'm reminded of Bogle's insistence in Enough. of how crucial it is to focus on the thing you can't count (like reputation) over the things you can count (like quarterly sales).

Anyways! Like I said up top, I really enjoyed this book. Reading it takes a big investment (heh) in time, but it's low-risk and offers significant rewards: practical guidance on personal financial planning, a deep understanding of how markets work, and a wide-ranging, insightful survey of the mutual fund industry and the people it employs and serves. The more I read and hear from Bogle the more I admire him. Even if he's gone, and even if his version of Vanguard is fading, he's left behind an extraordinary legacy in the way individual investors think and behave.